Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nr4z6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-12T12:45:29.027Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Class Structure, Labor Market Heterogeneity, and Living Conditions in Latin America

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2022

Patricio Solís*
Affiliation:
El Colegio de México, MX
Eduardo Chávez Molina
Affiliation:
University of Buenos Aires, AR
Daniel Cobos
Affiliation:
El Colegio de México, MX
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We analyze class structures in Latin America from a sociological perspective, defining social classes as labor market positions. We propose an adaptation of the Erikson-Goldthorpe-Portocarero (EGP) class schema, which has become a standard in advanced industrialized countries but presents some limitations in accounting for labor relations in Latin America. Then, we use recent survey data for nine Latin American countries to delineate a map of current class structures and explore the association between social class and social/economic conditions. Our results indicate that class structures differ significantly not only between Latin America and advanced industrialized nations but also among Latin American countries. There is also a close association between class membership and socioeconomic conditions, including social protection and the risk of poverty. These results suggest that a sociological approach to social class is still pertinent to understanding the relationships among productive structures, labor markets, and living conditions in Latin America.

En este trabajo analizamos las estructuras de clase en América Latina (AL) desde una perspectiva sociológica, que define las clases sociales como posiciones en el mercado de trabajo. Proponemos adaptar el esquema de Erikson-Goldthorpe-Portocarero (EGP), que es de uso generalizado en países de industrialización temprana, pero tiene algunas limitaciones para dar cuenta de las relaciones de trabajo en AL. Luego, usamos datos recientes de encuestas de nueve países de AL para delinear un mapa de las estructuras de clase y explorar la asociación entre la pertenencia de clase y las condiciones sociales y económicas. Nuestros resultados indican que las estructuras de clase no sólo difieren significativamente entre AL y los países de industrialización temprana, sino también entre países latinoamericanos. Existe además una asociación estrecha entre la pertenencia de clase y las condiciones sociales y económicas, entre ellas la protección social y el riesgo de pobreza. Esto sugiere que una mirada sociológica a las clases sociales es todavía pertinente para entender las relaciones entre las estructuras productivas, los mercados de trabajo y las condiciones de vida en AL.

Type
Sociology
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (CC-BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. See http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
Copyright
Copyright: © 2019 The Author(s)

Sociological research on class stratification and mobility has reemerged in Latin America. After an initial boom in the 1960s and 1970s (Reference Germani, Lipset and BendixGermani 1963; Reference Labbens and SolariLabbens and Solari 1961; Reference RaczynskiRaczynski 1972; Reference Balán, Browning and JelinBalán, Browning, and Jelin 1977; Reference Muñoz and de OliveiraMuñoz and Oliveira 1973; Reference PastorePastore 1979), followed by few developments during the 1980s and 1990s, several studies have been published in recent years (Reference ScalonScalon 1999; Reference Pastore and do Valle SilvaPastore and Do Valle Silva 2000; Reference León and MartínezLeón and Martínez 2001; Reference BenavidesBenavides 2002; Reference Torche and WormaldTorche and Wormald 2004; Reference TorcheTorche 2005; Reference SolísSolís 2005; Reference Cortés and EscobarCortés and Escobar 2005; Reference EspinozaEspinoza 2006; Reference JorratJorrat 2000, Reference Jorrat2008; Reference Costa RibeiroCosta Ribeiro 2007; Reference BoadoBoado 2008; Reference TorcheTorche 2014; Reference Solís and BoadoSolís and Boado 2016). These studies have increased our understanding of class structures and intergenerational class mobility patterns in the region.

Parallel to sociological research, economists have also developed a new interest in social class and social mobility (Reference Behrman, Gaviria, Székely, Birdsall and GalianiBehrman et al. 2001; Reference Gaviria and DahanGaviria and Dahan 2001; Reference Ferreira, Messina, Rigolini, López-Calva, Lugo and VakisFerreira et al. 2012; Reference López-Calva and Ortiz-JuarezLópez-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez 2014). There is an obvious overlap in research topics between sociological and economic studies. However, integration and cross-disciplinary efforts are scarce. This is explained in part by disciplinary differences in the theoretical approach to social class and mobility (Reference GruskyGrusky and Kanbur 2006). Most sociological studies adopt a structural approach and define social classes as groups of similar occupational positions in the labor market, under the assumption that these positions regulate access to unequal “reward packages” in a multidimensional space of resources or “social rewards” (e.g., income, social protection, power, prestige) (Reference WrightWright 1997; Reference Grusky and GruskyGrusky 1994; Reference TorcheTorche 2006). From this perspective, occupational mobility is interpreted as social mobility. In contrast, economic studies define social classes as statistical strata in a distribution of income, wealth, or other economic resources, or alternatively on the basis of patterns and levels of consumption. In the economic approach, social mobility takes place when individuals or families experience changes in their position in this distribution, across either a continuous scale or predefined thresholds that mark the limits between strata (i.e., mobility from “poverty” to “the middle class”) (Reference Fields and OkFields and Ok 1996).

The sociological approach to social class highlights the role of occupational positions as institutionalized entities that mediate between individuals and social rewards.Footnote 1 These structural foundations are obscured in the economic approach, which focuses directly on the position of individuals or families in the distribution of income, wealth, or other economic resources. On the other hand, a defining trait of the sociological approach is that the association between class membership and living conditions is probabilistic, not deterministic. Given that sociological classes are defined in the space of labor market positions, the extent of this association depends on the correlation between these positions and distributional inequalities, a correlation that is assumed by sociologists but not often empirically analyzed (Reference GruskyGrusky and Kanbur 2006), particularly in Latin America (Reference Solís and BoadoSolís and Boado 2016).Footnote 2 Members of the same “sociological” class may be located in different regions of the distribution of income or other economic resources and therefore belong to different economic strata. This characteristic is problematic for economists, who are mainly interested on directly describing inequalities in economic conditions, and therefore view the sociological approach as an inefficient method to characterize such inequalities.

In summary, sociological class analysis emphasizes the structural foundations of social positions but offers only an indirect approach to distributional inequalities. Consequently, the utility of class analysis in studies of inequality depends on the strength of the empirical association between class membership and the distribution of resources, both economic and not economic. The goal of this article is precisely to demonstrate that a sociological approach to social class in Latin America not only is relevant to characterize labor market positions and identify national similarities and differences in class structures but also contributes to understand social and economic inequalities.

To achieve this, a first step is to discuss the concept of social class and its empirical implementation in the Latin American context. In advanced industrialized societies, the Erikson-Goldthorpe-Portocarero (EGP) class schema (Reference Erikson, Goldthorpe and PortocareroErikson, Goldthorpe, and Portocarero 1979; Reference Goldthorpe, Halsey, Heath, Ridge, Bloom and JonesGoldthorpe et al. 1982; Reference Erikson and GoldthorpeErikson and Goldthorpe 1992) has become a standard among sociologists working in the field of social stratification and mobility. This schema was developed initially for European countries but has been extensively used in other regions of the world, including Latin America. Even when labor conditions in European labor markets have deteriorated in recent decades, particularly among youth (Reference Breman and LindenBreman and Linden 2014; Reference BlossfeldBlossfeld 2008), and some Latin American countries experienced an improvement in labor conditions during the 2000s (Reference WellerWeller 2014), the gaps between these two regions in terms of the heterogeneity of productive structures and the segmentation of labor markets is still significant. Therefore, an important question is whether a class schema such as EGP is appropriate to depict the specific features of Latin American class structures.

In the next section we briefly describe the EGP schema and discuss its main limitations to characterize occupational positions in Latin America. This leads us to propose an adapted version of the EGP schema that attempts to solve these shortcomings. We use this adapted schema to conduct an empirical description of class structures and the association between social class and social conditions in nine Latin American countries (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Ecuador, El Salvador, Mexico, Nicaragua, Peru, and Uruguay), including selected markers of social protection and monetary income.

The EGP Class Schema in Latin America: Limitations and Proposed Adaptations

The EGP class schema was designed to analyze the process of class formation through social mobility in Western European countries (Reference Erikson, Goldthorpe and PortocareroErikson, Goldthorpe, and Portocarero 1979; Reference Goldthorpe, Halsey, Heath, Ridge, Bloom and JonesGoldthorpe et al. 1982; Reference Erikson and GoldthorpeErikson and Goldthorpe 1992). The theoretical approach was, according to its creators, “in its inspiration rather eclectic … drawn on ideas, whatever their source, that appeared to [be] helpful in forming class categories capable of displaying the salient features of mobility among the populations of modern industrial societies—and within the limits set by the (available) data” (Reference Erikson and GoldthorpeErikson and Goldthorpe 1992, 35). In this sense, even when the influence of Marx and Weber is directly acknowledged by the authors, the resulting scheme should not be considered as a theoretical exercise but as an “instrument de travail” (Reference Erikson and GoldthorpeErikson and Goldthorpe 1992, 46), a tool for empirical research.

The point of departure is the distinction of three major class positions: (1) employers, or those who hire the labor of others; (2) self-employed without employees, or independent workers who neither buy the labor of others nor sell their own; and (3) employees, or those who sell their labor to employers. In addition to this primary division, a second major distinction is introduced among employees, between those who are engaged in labor contract or service labor relations. This separation captures the differentiation in labor relations among salaried workers in modern capitalism noted by sociologists such as Renner and Dahrendorf, between the traditional working class, composed of manual workers with labor contracts based on a short-term exchange of money for labor under conditions of direct supervision, and a service class, composed fundamentally of managerial and supervisory staff and professionals who are engaged in longer-term salaried relationships and often possess a higher degree of autonomy, some extent of delegated authority, and specialized skills.

Two characteristics of the EGP schema are particularly important for our discussion. First, the key principle of classification is the type of labor relationship. To be clear, the schema uses other characteristics (i.e., distinctions between manual and nonmanual or skilled and unskilled workers), but these distinctions are either a proxy of predominant labor relationships in certain groups of occupations or a source of secondary distinctions. Second, even when the EGP scheme was inspired on theoretical ideas, it was mainly guided by contextual and practical considerations in two major respects: an evaluation of the predominant labor relations in advanced capitalist societies and a series of empirical criteria of classification based on an “ideal-typical” association between labor relationships and groups of occupations.

We acknowledge that labor relations must be the principal criterion for elaborating a class schema, but we argue that labor relations are more heterogeneous in Latin America than in advanced industrialized nations, and therefore the “ideal-typical” association between labor relationships and occupations described by Goldthorpe and colleagues for these countries does not hold in Latin America for certain groups of occupations.

Latin American Labor Markets, Limitations of the EGP Schema, and Proposed Adaptations

Several studies in Latin America have adopted the EGP schema (Reference TorcheTorche 2005; Reference Costa RibeiroCosta Ribeiro 2007; Reference Espinoza, Barozet and MéndezEspinoza, Barozet, and Méndez 2013; Reference Solís and BoadoSolís and Boado 2016).Footnote 3 The use of this schema has been crucial to introduce the “Latin American case” to the academic discussion on intergenerational class mobility taking place in advanced industrialized nations. However, advances in comparability might have come at a high price because this schema fails to adequately capture three important sources of heterogeneity in Latin American labor markets: the distinction between formal and informal salaried workers, the heterogeneous job conditions among self-employed workers, and the conformation of a separate class integrated by economic and bureaucratic elites.

The distinction between formal and informal salaried workers derives from the important role of the informal sector in the structuration of labor relations in Latin America. There are two predominant perspectives of the informal sector (Reference Portes and SchaufflerPortes and Schauffler 1993; Reference Cortés and de la Garza ToledoCortés 2000; Reference Gasparini and TornarolliGasparini and Tornarolli 2009): the structuralist or productive perspective and the regulationist perspective. The structuralist perspective focuses on the heterogeneity in productivity levels among firms and defines informal workers as those in low-productivity firms (Reference TokmanTokman 1992, Reference Tokman1995). This structural heterogeneity was initially described by Latin American economists and structural sociologists such as Prebisch, Furtado, and Pinto (Reference Di Filippo and JadueDi Filippo y Jadue 1976; Reference Feito AlonsoFeito Alonso 1995; Reference PintoPinto 1973) as a situation in which two economic sectors coexist, one with high productivity, closer to that of advanced industrialized nations but unable to absorb the complete labor force, and the other in which productivity levels are much lower and subsistence economic activities prevail. The regulationist perspective emphasizes labor conditions and defines informal jobs as those that are not legally or formally regulated and therefore do not offer job protection and benefits (Reference Portes, Castells, Benton, Portes, Castells and BentonPortes et al. 1989).

In this article, we adopt the structuralist perspective because we are interested on highlighting the effects of Latin America’s heterogeneity of productive units on class formation and labor conditions, including the regulation of labor. Employers in the high-productivity or “formal” sector have incentives to offer relatively better wages and labor conditions, to retain the more productive labor force, reduce conflict, increase skills and, through these actions, increase productivity (Reference WellerWeller 2000, 33). In contrast, in the low-productivity or “informal” sector, labor relations are not guided by productivity demands or an interest to retain skilled or experienced workers but by supply factors and survival strategies. Labor relations are often embedded in kinship, friendship, or acquaintance ties, and salaries, job benefits, and job security tend to be significantly lower than in the formal sector.

Thus, we conceive the heterogeneity of productive units as a determinant of heterogeneous labor relations and distributional outcomes, including the regulation of contracts, access to social security, and inequality in wages (Reference Chávez Molina, Sacco, Lindemboim and SalviaChávez Molina and Sacco 2015). This association would be concealed if we adopted the regulationist perspective, because indicators of labor regulation (e.g., a written labor contract, access to social security) would be considered as a defining feature of class membership, not as a consequence of it.

The diversity in labor relations associated with structural heterogeneity is not captured by the original EGP scheme. Among salaried workers, the EGP scheme considers only the distinction between “service” and “labor contract” relations. We propose including an additional distinction between workers in formal and informal firms. This distinction is particularly relevant for manual salaried workers, but it also applies to routine nonmanual workers, and specifically to sales employees, where heterogeneity in productive units and labor conditions is higher (Reference Cortés and CuéllarCortés and Cuéllar 1990).Footnote 4

A second characteristic of Latin American labor markets is the heterogeneity in labor conditions among self-employed workers. The EGP scheme divides self-employed workers in three groups: first, the class of agricultural self-employed workers (IVc), a category originally devised to include independent farmers with relatively high productivity levels in advanced industrialized nations, but in most Latin American countries mainly comprises peasants in subsistence farming or with very low productivity levels. Second, independent professionals, who are engaged in freelance service labor relations and therefore classified in the service class. Finally, self-employed workers in nonagricultural positions (IVb).

In Latin America, class IVb incorporates a very heterogeneous mix of occupations. It includes specialized manual workers who offer their services as freelancers, but also unskilled workers in a variety of activities, such as street sales, food vending, or cleaning services, who are subject to insecure work conditions and often engage in disguised precarious salaried labor relations. Unskilled self-employed occupations of this kind have also been linked to the expansion of the informal sector, because they often represent an alternative to the absence of employment opportunities (or at least well-paid opportunities) in formal firms. We argue that labor conditions and remunerations are significantly different for skilled and unskilled self-employed workers, and therefore suggest creating a division within class IVb to account for these differences.

Finally, we propose a third distinction at the top of the EGP class scheme (class I). In advanced industrialized countries, the expansion and increasing heterogeneity of the higher service class has led some researchers to suggest a subdivision between large employers and high-level managers, on the one hand, and professionals, on the other. The arguments for this distinction have been that these two groups are engaged in different labor relations, are subject to different mobility patterns, and even present contrasting political attitudes (Reference Güveli, Need and De GraafGüveli, Need, and De Graaf 2007; Reference Gerber and HoutGerber and Hout 2004). This distinction is probably also important in Latin America, where economic and political elites not only are more privileged in economic and social conditions, but also separate themselves from professionals in patterns of social reproduction and intergenerational mobility (Reference TorcheTorche 2005; Reference Solís and BoadoSolís y Boado 2016).

As a result of the previous discussion, we introduce several adaptations to the EGP scheme. These adaptations are summarized in Table 1. First, we divide manual salaried employees (V+VI and VIIa) into groups of formal and informal workers. We propose a similar distinction for lower-grade routine nonmanual employees (IIIb), a group comprising mostly sales workers. Second, we separate skilled or semiskilled from unskilled and self-employed workers. Finally, at the top of the class structure we distinguish large employers, high-level managers, and professionals with employees from salaried and self-employed professionals. As we have discussed, this adaptation creates a separate group for economic and bureaucratic elites.Footnote 5

Table 1 Adjustments to the EGP social class schema for Latin America.

In Table 2 we present a complete version of the adapted EGP schema. The schema consists of fifteen groups collapsed into six “macro” classes: the service class, formal routine nonmanual workers, small employers and independent workers, formal salaried workers, informal salaried and self-employed workers, and agricultural classes. This schema is compatible either with a ten-class or a seven-class version of the original EGP schema, thus allowing for comparability with other studies.

Table 2 Adapted EGP schema for Latin America.

Data and Methods

We use data from household surveys conducted by national statistical offices. We defined three requirements for inclusion of countries in our analysis: the data and documentation were available to the public; the surveys were conducted in the period 2011–2015; and the surveys included sufficient information to derive the proposed class scheme as well as selected indicators of social protection and household income. Our final sample includes nine countries: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Ecuador, El Salvador, Mexico, Nicaragua, Peru, and Uruguay. With the exception of Argentina, all surveys have a national geographic coverage. The appendix presents the most relevant methodological characteristics of these surveys.

The adapted EGP schema was generated using information on the respondents’ current occupation, occupational position, and size of the firm. We classified workers in the informal sector using as a proxy the size of the firm, with a cutoff point of ten workers. This approach is frequent in empirical studies adopting the productivist approach. Productivity levels cannot be assessed with standard household surveys, and previous research has shown that there is a direct link between firm size and productivity in Latin America.Footnote 6

The crossing of this information produced a comparable classification of the working population in each country according to the schema presented in Table 2. We use this adjusted EGP schema to create a map of class structures across Latin American countries.

We propose to analyze class inequalities across two dimensions: social protection and income. Most national household surveys collect information in these two dimensions. However, the specific questions and methods of recollection vary significantly across countries. To maximize the number of countries included, we restricted our analysis to a limited number of variables and indicators.

In the case of social protection, we focus on three variables: labor contract protection, inclusion in a retirement pension program, and health insurance coverage. For labor contract protection, we classified salaried workers according to whether they have a signed labor contract. In the case of retirement pensions, we identified salaried workers contributing or not to a public or private pension fund.Footnote 7 The third indicator (access to health insurance) is not restricted to salaried workers, because in several Latin American countries individuals can have access to public or private health insurance either as a job benefit or through other means.Footnote 8

As regards monetary income, we work with the household per capita income. A methodological problem is that our definition of social class is measured at the individual level, and therefore one household may include working individuals with different class positions. On the basis of previous research (Reference Solís and BenzaSolís and Benza 2013; Reference Davies, Elias, Rose and HarrisonDavies and Elias 2010), we assigned each household a class position according to the following set of rules: For households with only one working member, we assigned the social class of that member. For households with two or more working members, we assigned the class of the member with the highest monetary income. For households with no working members, we created a separate group of households with no working members.Footnote 9

We use the calculations of household income provided by the national statistical offices and included in the microdata files. There are significant methodological differences across countries in these calculations. For example, there is variation in the phrasing and scope of questions used to register the different sources of income. There are also differences in reference periods, in the inclusion of different sources of income, in the way tax deductions are managed, and in the use of explicit or implicit methods of imputation.

As Beccaría (Reference Beccaría2007) concluded after analyzing a previous round (1990–2004) of household Latin American surveys, these methodological differences may significantly affect the comparability of estimations. However, comparability problems are more likely to arise if we try to contrast absolute income levels rather than the relative position of classes in the income distribution. For this reason, our analysis is based exclusively on relative indicators of income.

The first indicator is the relative income share by social class. It is defined as the ratio of the proportion of national household income received by households in a class to the proportion of households in that same class. By definition, this ratio in the overall population is 1. A value larger than 1 indicates that a class is receiving more income than it would receive were the allocation of income proportional to its population size. Because relative income shares are adjusted both by the overall amount of income and by the size of classes registered in each country, they can be used to analyze income gaps among classes between countries.

The second indicator is relative poverty. We adopt a common definition of relative poverty and classify a poor household as that with a current per capita income below 60 percent of the overall national median income. Because median income values have important variations across Latin American countries, relative poverty should not be interpreted as an absolute measure of deprivation. Instead, it indicates that the household is located at the bottom of the income distribution, and therefore suffers a relative disadvantage compared to other households in the same country. Therefore, the proportion of households in relative poverty is comparable across social classes and countries.

Results

Class Structures in Latin America

Table 3 presents the class structures for nine Latin American countries, according to our adapted EGP class schema. Considering their similarities and differences, countries can be classified into three groups: Southern Cone countries (Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay); Brazil and Mexico; and Central American and Andean countries (Ecuador, El Salvador, Nicaragua, and Peru).

Table 3 Class structure in Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Note: Estimates are based on microdata from national household surveys (see Table A1).

* Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

Southern Cone countries are characterized by relatively high numbers of individuals in the service class (21–24 percent) and the “administrative class” of routine nonmanual formal workers (15 percent). The proportion of salaried manual workers in the formal sector is also higher than in other Latin American countries (22–27 percent). There is also a significant number of manual workers in the informal sector (15–26 percent);Footnote 10 however, the informal sector is not as predominant as in other Latin American countries. Finally, the proportions of workers in agricultural classes are the smallest in our sample of Latin American countries (8 percent in Uruguay and 9 percent in Chile).

In Brazil and Mexico, the proportions of members of the service class (18 percent in both countries) and routine nonmanual class (12.9 percent and 9.3 percent, respectively) are lower than in Southern Cone countries. A second important distinction is that the informal sector plays a more important part in the provision of work opportunities for manual workers. Salaried and self-employed informal workers account for 24.1 percent and 29.5 percent of the working population, respectively, as compared to 19.5 percent and 18.0 percent of salaried formal workers. Finally, the relative weight of agricultural classes is also slightly higher, with proportions of 12.7 percent in Brazil and 10.8 percent in Mexico.

The class structures of Central American and Andean countries are characterized by the importance of agricultural classes (22.4 percent on average and as high as 27.4 percent in Nicaragua). Among manual nonagricultural workers, informal positions are predominant. On average, 24.6 percent of the working population is classified as informal salaried or self-employed workers, as compared to only 17.9 percent of manual salaried formal workers. In contrast, the service and administrative classes present lower expansion levels compared to the other two groups of countries.

In Brazil and Mexico, the proportions of members of the service class (18 percent in both countries) and routine nonmanual class (12.9 percent and 9.3 percent, respectively) are lower than in Southern Cone countries. A second important distinction is that the informal sector plays a more important part in the provision of work opportunities for manual workers. Salaried and self-employed informal workers account for 24.1 percent and 29.5 percent of the working population, respectively, as compared to 19.5 percent and 18.0 percent of salaried formal workers. Finally, the relative weight of agricultural classes is also slightly higher, with proportions of 12.7 percent in Brazil and 10.8 percent in Mexico.

Finally, the class structures of Central American and Andean countries are characterized by the importance of agricultural classes (22.4 percent on average, and as high as 27.4 percent in Nicaragua). Among manual nonagricultural workers, informal positions are predominant. On average, 24.6 percent of the working population is classified as informal salaried or self-employed workers, as compared to only 17.9 percent of manual salaried formal workers. In contrast, the service and administrative classes present lower expansion levels compared to the other two groups of countries.

A detailed analysis of these national differences is beyond the scope of this article. However, three preliminary conclusions are in order. First, this characterization suggests that, rather than converging into a common Latin American pattern, the current map of class structures in Latin America is highly heterogeneous. Second, the differences in class structures among the three groups of countries seem to be related to their distinctive historical patterns of capitalist development, urbanization, and labor market transformation.

Compared to the rest of Latin America, Southern Cone countries show the highest levels of urbanization, a relatively advanced development of the manufacturing and service sectors, and a historical record of higher labor market regulation. These characteristics seem to have generated more favorable conditions for the expansion of urban service and administrative classes as well as a robust formal working class.

In contrast, Central American and Andean countries present the lowest levels of urbanization, a relatively weak development of the manufacturing and service sectors, and serious limitations to the creation of high-productivity labor-market positions. Consequently, the urban service and administrative classes represent only a minor fraction of the population, informal manual positions are predominant, and agricultural classes still represent a large fraction of the population.

Brazil and Mexico, the two most populated nations in Latin America, share with the countries of the Southern Cone a history of strong domestic industrialization and later expansion of the service sector. But they are also more internally diverse in terms of their regional patterns and levels of socioeconomic development and urbanization. Their class structures seem to reflect this diversity and adhere to a pattern located somewhat in between Southern Cone and Central American and Andean countries.

The third conclusion is that, despite the national differences just described, when compared with advanced industrialized nations, the class structures of Latin American countries are characterized by two general features: the segmentation of nonagricultural manual classes in the formal and informal sector and the underdevelopment of the urban service and administrative classes.Footnote 11 These two characteristics impose structural constrains to the expansion of urban middle-income strata.

Class and Social Protection

In addition to mapping current class structures in Latin America, we have proposed analyzing the association of class membership, social protection, and relative income. In this section we focus on social protection. Two of the three variables we have proposed (access to a written labor contract and pension coverage) can be alternatively interpreted as indicators of job security or, from the opposite point of view, precarity among salaried workers (Reference WresinskiWresinski 1987; Reference De Oliveira and GarcíaDe Oliveira y García 1998).Footnote 12 In contrast, access to health insurance is a more general measure of social protection available for the entire adult population in all countries, with the exception of Brazil.

Perhaps the most severe marker of job insecurity among salaried workers is the absence of a written labor contract (Table 4). Argentina and Uruguay do not include in their surveys specific questions about access to a written labor contract. However, the high levels of salaried workers contributing to pension plans (see Table 5) suggest that the two countries, along with Chile (where 80.9 percent of salaried workers have a written labor contract), present the highest proportions of salaried workers with contract protection in the region. In contrast, these proportions are much lower in Central American countries (34.8 percent in El Salvador and 32.5 percent in Nicaragua), followed by Mexico and Peru.

Table 4 Percentage of salaried workers with written labor contract by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Note: Estimates based on microdata from national household surveys (see Table A1).

* Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

Table 5 Percentage of workers contributing to a pension plan by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Note: Estimates based on microdata from national household surveys (see Table A1).

* Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

What is the association between social class and contract protection? On average, the highest levels of contract protection are for the service class (82.6 percent) and formal routine nonmanual workers (79.9 percent). In the other extreme, the lowest levels are for salaried and family workers in agriculture, with an average of 17.2 percent and coverage levels under 10 percent in El Salvador, Mexico, Nicaragua, and Peru.Footnote 13

There is a significant gap between formal and informal salaried classes. On average, 77.8 percent of salaried workers in the formal sector have a written labor contract, as compared to 23.4 percent of informal salaried workers—that is, a coverage gap of 3.3 to 1. This gap is wider in Central American countries, Peru, and Mexico, with protection levels between 6.3 and 17.2 times higher for manual workers in the formal sector. Distances are still important but smaller in Ecuador (85 percent to 43 percent), Brazil (88 percent to 39 percent) and Chile (87 percent to 57 percent).

The distinction by skill level is also important. On average, 82.1 percent of skilled or semiskilled manual workers in the formal sector had a written labor contract, as compared to 73.7 percent of unskilled manual workers. This gap in coverage, always in favor of skilled or semiskilled workers, fluctuates between 2 percent (Peru) and 27 percent (Ecuador). For informal manual workers the skill gap is more important, with coverage by a written labor contract on average 61 percent higher for skilled or semiskilled workers, and variations between 14 percent (Chile) and 166 percent (Ecuador). In sum, qualifications and skills also seem to affect the chances of access to a written labor contract, particularly in the informal sector. However, differences are of lower magnitude than those associated with the formal-informal divide.

The number of workers contributing to a pension plan (Table 5) fluctuates between 27 percent in Nicaragua and 87 percent in Uruguay. The three Southern Cone countries show the highest coverage levels, followed by Brazil (60 percent). In the other five countries the fraction of covered workers is lower than 50 percent. In addition to these national differences, in all countries there is a significant association between social class and incorporation to retirement pension programs. Again, coverage levels are higher for the service class and formal routine nonmanual workers, with averages around 80 percent, followed by salaried manual workers in the formal sector (76.2 percent). Access to pension plans is drastically reduced among informal manual workers, with 24.7 percent, that is, a coverage ratio of 3 to 1 in favor of formal salaried workers. In Ecuador, El Salvador, Mexico, Nicaragua, and Peru the gap between formal and informal workers is even larger. The largest estimated gap is in Nicaragua, where only 3.4 percent of informal workers contribute to pension plans, as compared to 69.6 percent of formal manual workers. Finally, with the exception of Southern Cone countries, agricultural workers present the lowest coverage levels, with proportions below 10 percent.

In Mexico, Brazil, and Chile, where we have information of access to pension plans for small employers and self-employed workers, our results indicate that coverage levels for workers in these positions are lower in relation to other social classes. Thus, even in countries where access to pension plans is open for independent workers, effective coverage levels are low and the gap in access to pension programs between self-employed and salaried workers remains.

Finally, in relation to health insurance (Table 6), there is great variability in national health systems, in terms of both the extent and mechanisms of incorporation and the levels of segmentation within health institutions (Reference Wagstaff, Cotlear, Eozenou and BuismanWagstaff et al. 2016; Reference Cotlear, Gómez-Dantés, Knaul, Atun, Barreto, Cetrángolo, Cueto, Francke, Frenz, Guerrero, Lozano, Marten and SáenzCotlear et al. 2015; Reference Londoño and FrenkLondoño and Frenk 1997). In Brazil, Mexico, and Uruguay, public health insurance programs have high coverage levels, but the quality and effective access to services is highly segmented either geographically or according to the type of coverage (Reference Jaimes and FlamandJaimes and Flamand 2016). Other countries, such as Argentina, have lower coverage rates but offer universal access to a complementary network of public services, again with very unequal quality (Reference CetrángoloCetrángolo 2014). Additionally, in most countries affluent classes have access to private health insurance plans. This complexity deserves a more detailed analysis that is out of reach of this article. However, we can explore differences by social class using a simple variable of access to a health insurance plan (either public or private) as a broad indicator of medical protection.

Table 6 Percentage of workers subscribed to a health insurance plan* by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Note: Estimates based on microdata from household surveys (see Table A1).

* Includes membership to public or private plans. Does not include public health services with open access for the overall population.

** Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

*** No information available in national survey.

With the exception of Uruguay and Chile, where health insurance is almost universal (98 percent and 95 percent, respectively) and therefore inequalities reduced to a minimum, in all other countries the levels of coverage vary significantly across social classes, and particularly among formal and informal workers. Coverage levels are very similar for the service class (82.0 percent on average), formal routine nonmanual workers (84.3 percent) and formal salaried manual workers (82.1 percent). In contrast, in most countries informal workers present much lower coverage levels, with an average of 47.9 percent, similar to that observed among agricultural workers (51.9 percent). The formal-informal divide is particularly high in Nicaragua, El Salvador, and Ecuador, but there are also significant differences in Argentina, Peru, and Mexico.

Class, Income Inequality, and Relative Income Poverty

We now analyze the association between social class and household income.Footnote 14 The first measure is the relative income share (Table 7). Despite the underreporting problem among high-income households, in all countries the service class absorbs the highest income shares, with levels fluctuating between 1.5 (Argentina) and 2.1 (Brazil). Within the service class, the group of lower-grade administrators, professionals, and technicians has a lower income share than large proprietors, higher-grade administrators, and professionals.

Table 7 Relative income share of household per capita income by social class, Latin American countries, 2011–2015.

Note: The social class of the household is defined as that of the principal earner among working household members. Estimates based on microdata from national household surveys (see Table A1).

* Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

Two other social classes concentrate average income shares larger than the average. One is the “administrative” class of formal routine nonmanual workers, with an average income share of 1.13. It must be noted, however, that in Chile and Brazil routine nonmanual workers present income shares similar or lower than the average, indicating that in these two countries their economic position is less advantaged and lower in relation to the service class. The other class with an income share higher than average is small employers and independent workers (income share = 1.06). A closer look shows that high relative income levels in this class are mostly explained by small employers, with income shares significantly higher than 1 in all countries, except Mexico.Footnote 15 In contrast, self-employed workers in skilled occupations present an average income share of 0.69.

In all countries, salaried workers in the formal sector, salaried and self-employed workers in the informal sector, and agricultural workers concentrate a lower proportion of income than their population size. However, there are important differences among these three classes. Salaried workers in the formal sector present the highest income share (average of 0.82), followed by workers in the informal sector (0.64), and agricultural workers (0.49). The magnitude of these gaps varies in each country, but the hierarchical ordering prevails. This pattern confirms the importance of the formal-informal-rural class divide to explain distributional inequalities at the bottom of the income distribution in Latin America.

In contrast, differences between skilled and unskilled salaried workers in the formal and informal sectors are also important, but in most countries those differences are not as large as those associated with the formal-informal gap.Footnote 16 Thus, to explain income differentials among manual nonagricultural workers in Latin America, the sectoral division between formal and informal workers is as important as the distinction usually made in conventional class schemas between skilled and unskilled workers.

Table 8 presents the percentage of households in relative poverty by social class. Because households in relative poverty are those located at the lower end of the income distribution, it is not surprising to find similarities in trends with relative shares. In all countries, the risk of poverty is higher among agricultural classes, with an average incidence of 54.9 percent. In urban settings (among nonagricultural classes), informal manual workers are significantly more likely to be in relative poverty, with an average incidence of 35.3 percent and national levels as high as 48.7 percent in Argentina and 42.4 percent in Uruguay. Within this class, in most countries the highest prevalence of relative poverty is among unskilled self-employed workers. The exceptions are Argentina and Brazil, where unskilled salaried informal workers are in a higher risk than the other groups. The prevalence of relative poverty is much lower among formal salaried workers (20.5 percent on average), and within this class, skilled workers do significantly better, with risks of poverty on average 40 percent lower than unskilled workers.

Table 8 Percentage of households in relative poverty by social class, Latin American countries, 2011–2015.

Note: Households in relative poverty are defined as those with a per capita income lower than 60 percent of the median. The social class of the household is defined as that of the principal earner among working household members. Estimates based on microdata from national household surveys (see Table A1).

* Sample includes only thirty-one urban areas (70 percent of national urban population).

Relative poverty among small employers and independent workers is on average 24.5 percent. This figure is higher than expected given the high relative share of income for this class (see Table 7). This indicates that even when the average income levels are higher in this class than, for example, among formal manual workers, there is a higher dispersion in income and a larger proportion of members of this class are at the lower part of the income distribution. This dispersion is mostly explained by the heterogeneity in incomes among self-employed skilled workers. The relative income share of this group is 0.85, slightly higher than the 0.82 of formal salaried workers, but the prevalence of relative poverty is 27.9 percent, significantly higher than the 20.5 percent of formal salaried workers.

Finally, the risk of relative poverty is the lowest among the service class (6.4 percent on average) and routine nonmanual workers in the formal sector (10.9 percent).Footnote 17 An overall view of the cross-class variation in the prevalence of relative poverty in each country indicates that in Latin America only these two social classes are relatively free of the risk of relative income poverty. At the other extreme, agricultural workers and informal nonagricultural workers (particularly those in unskilled self-employed and salaried occupations) are the most vulnerable to poverty.

Discussion and Conclusions

Two central arguments of this article are that class structures in Latin America present specific characteristics that distinguish them from advanced industrialized nations, and to draw a map of social class in Latin America and evaluate the association between class and socioeconomic conditions, these specific features must be incorporated into class schemas currently used by sociologists to study social stratification in advanced industrialized societies.

We proposed a class schema to characterize class structures in Latin America. Our point of departure was the EGP schema, created originally by Erikson and Goldthorpe for Western European societies and extensively used in international comparative research on social stratification and mobility. We preserved the key conceptual and empirical components of this schema but introduced additional distinctions specific to Latin American societies.

The most important distinction is between formal and informal workers. Latin American economies are characterized by structural heterogeneity, that is, the coexistence of a formal sector with relatively high productivity levels and an informal sector characterized by low productivity and survival activities. This segmentation implies that individuals in apparently similar occupational positions are involved in different labor relations depending on whether they belong to the formal or the informal segment of the economy.

This distinction, along with other minor adjustments, such as the subdivision of the service class and the reordering of independent agricultural workers at the bottom of the class structure, led us to propose a class schema with fifteen groups, which can be collapsed into either the traditional ten-class EGP schema or a six-class collapsed class schema.

On the basis of this adapted schema, in the empirical part of this article we used national household surveys to characterize class structures across nine Latin American countries. In addition, we obtained comparable information on social protection (labor contract, access to retirement pension plans and health insurance coverage), as well as on household income and relative poverty, to assess social and economic inequalities between classes.

We highlight two conclusions from our empirical findings. First, there is great diversity in class structures across Latin American countries, and therefore any effort to classify all countries in the region under a “Latin American class structure” might be misleading. Instead, our analysis suggests that countries can be classified in three groups: Southern Cone countries (Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay), Brazil and Mexico, and Central American and Andean countries (Ecuador, El Salvador, Nicaragua, and Peru).

Compared to the rest of Latin America, Southern Cone countries stand out by the expansion of managerial, professional, and routine nonmanual positions. Larger numbers of nonagricultural manual workers are in the formal sector, and agricultural classes represent only a minor fraction of the population. In contrast, class structures in Central American and Andean countries are defined by a much larger proportion of members in the agricultural classes, the preponderance of the informal sector in nonagricultural manual positions, and a relatively small expansion of the service and nonmanual administrative classes. Brazil and Mexico, with higher internal diversity, present class distributions with proportions located between the other two groups.

Despite the aforementioned differences, a common feature of Latin American countries is the relative small size of the service class and the class of formal salaried routine nonmanual workers. Even for Southern Cone countries, where the expansion of these two classes has been the largest, their overall share is much lower than in advanced industrialized countries.

We have suggested that the grouping of countries according to their similarities and differences in class structures might be explained by their historical paths of capitalist development, labor-market transformation, and urbanization. This interpretation, however, must be validated by additional research, which we plan to address in future studies. A detailed reconstruction of historical trends and intracountry regional differences, as well as the expansion of our analysis to a larger group of countries, could provide a more solid basis for developing a typology of class structures in Latin American countries. In addition, it is important to study whether there is an association between types of class structures and other macrosocial markers of differentiation in the region, since there is certain similarity between our grouping of countries and typologies of social policy or welfare regimes proposed by other studies (Reference Barba SolanoBarba Solano 2013; Reference Martínez FranzoniMartínez Franzoni 2006).

The second conclusion is that there is a strong association between social class, social protection, and monetary income, suggesting that class membership in Latin America is a strong predictor of social and economic conditions.Footnote 18 In most countries, access to a written labor contract, pension programs, and health insurance among salaried workers is highly dependent on their specific class position. Informal manual workers and salaried workers in agriculture are significantly more exposed to unprotected social conditions.Footnote 19 Relative income levels are lower and relative poverty significantly higher among informal salaried workers and agricultural classes. In contrast, the service class and routine nonmanual salaried workers in the formal sector experience better social conditions.

These results lead us back to our initial discussion on the differences between the sociological and economic approaches to social class. We finished this discussion with an open question about the pertinence of “sociological” social classes to study the structural foundations of social and economic inequality and poverty in Latin America. By establishing that there is a significant association between social class, social protection, income, and relative poverty, we have shown that a sociological approach to social class is still relevant to understand the relationships among productive structures, labor markets, and social/economic conditions.

An example of the pertinence of the sociological approach is its contribution to the ongoing debate about the expansion of the “middle class” in Latin America. Recent economic studies have shown that the middle class, defined as the fraction of the population escaping from income poverty, increased in Latin America during the first decade of the century (Reference Ferreira, Messina, Rigolini, López-Calva, Lugo and VakisFerreira et al. 2012; Reference López-Calva and Ortiz-JuarezLópez-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez 2014). With a different conceptual approach to social class, our analysis suggests that the low expansion of the service and routine nonmanual classes, as well as the persistence of high levels of inequality between formal and informal manual classes, represent serious structural constrains for further progress in this direction.

In sum, we believe that our proposal of an adapted class schema is a useful clarification and contributes to improve our understanding of class structures in Latin America, but at the same time creates challenges for future research. As we mentioned, it is necessary to extend our analysis to a larger number of countries. This will help validate our classification of countries in three groups and evaluate whether this classification effectively correspond to “ideal-typical” patterns of class structures. Second, our analysis is based on cross-sectional data and does not address the topic of class reproduction and class mobility. An analysis of intergenerational class mobility using the adapted EGP schema would indicate whether the proposed class distinctions are relevant to understanding the intergenerational reproduction of inequality. Finally, a third area for future exploration is the intersection of social class and other structural axes of social inequality, such as gender and race/ethnicity. We have shown that the association between social class and socioeconomic rewards is important but that at the same time there are important inequalities within social classes. An important question is whether other structural markers of social inequality can explain these intraclass disparities.

Appendix

Table A1 Data sources.

Acknowledgements

Part of this article was elaborated in the context of INCASI Network, a European project that has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program under the Marie Skłodowska-Curie GA No 691004. The article reflects only the authors’ view and the agency is not responsible for any use that may be made of the information it contains.

Footnotes

1 This emphasis is illustrated by an early passage of Schumpeter (Reference Schumpeter1955, 126) on social class and mobility: “Each class resembles a hotel or an omnibus, always full, but always of different people.”

2 However, see Savage et al. (Reference Savage, Devine, Cunningham, Taylor, Li, Hjellbrekke, Le Roux, Friedman and Miles2013), Wodtke (Reference Wodtke2016), and Rose and Harrison (Reference Rose and Harrison2014) for examples of recent studies that confirm the persistence of important distributional inequalities by social class in advanced industrialized nations.

3 It must be noted, however, that most of these studies have used the seven-class version and not the more detailed ten- or eleven-class version of the EGP scheme.

4 The distinction between formal and informal workers was considered in previous proposals of class schemas for Latin America (see, e.g., Reference PortesPortes 1985; Reference Portes and HoffmanPortes and Hoffman 2003; Reference Chávez MolinaChávez Molina 2013). However, these efforts were meant to generate ad hoc classifications. The resulting classifications were incompatible both conceptually and empirically with the EGP scheme. An exception is the work of Torche (Reference Torche2006), which uses the EGP scheme and evaluates whether it is necessary to incorporate a distinction between formal and informal workers for the Chilean case, finally ruling out the incorporation of such distinction. Torche’s decision is based on the empirical finding of high mobility between formal and informal positions. Our decision to incorporate the distinction is based on a different theoretical principle (the significant differences in labor relations and labor conditions among formal and informal workers). Later, in the empirical section, we validate this decision with data about labor conditions.

5 The privileged socioeconomic condition of political and economic elites is not fully represented in household surveys, because members of these classes are more difficult to reach and, when they accept to answer questionnaires, tend to underreport their income and wealth. This must be kept in mind when we empirically analyze the socioeconomic standing of these groups.

6 The size of the firm was proposed by ILO/PREALC (PREALC 1978) as a proxy of the informal sector in absence of data of other characteristics of the firm. In relation to the productivity gaps, a study by the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL 2010) indicates that the gaps in productivity levels between large and small firms are much higher in Latin America than in advanced industrialized countries. For example, according to this study (CEPAL 2010, 102), the average productivity of micro-sized and small firms in Latin America is equivalent to only 12 percent and 28 percent of the productivity of large firms, respectively; in contrast, in European countries the respective average gaps are only 57 percent and 68 percent.

7 Most national surveys restrict their questions on access to pensions to salaried workers, but in some countries (Brazil, Chile, and Mexico), these questions are asked of all respondents. In these countries we calculated access for all classes.

8 Unfortunately, in most national surveys it is not possible to establish whether pension and health insurance plans were public or private, so we were unable to make this distinction, which is important to establish the role of the welfare state and the market in distributional inequalities.

9 On average, 13.6 percent of households in our sample of Latin American countries have no working members but account for only 8.1 percent of the population, because they are smaller in size, with an average number of 2.0 members, as compared to 3.5 members for households with working members. Many households with no working members are integrated by elderly persons: the median age of the household head is sixty-six, as compared to forty for households with working members. The proportion of households with no working members varies significantly across countries and is related to population aging; it is around 20 percent in Argentina and Uruguay, and only 5.2 percent in Ecuador. The social class of these households could be derived from retrospective data about the occupation of their members. However, this information is not available in national surveys. Therefore, we decided to group them as a separate category.

10 Chile stands out as the only country in our sample where formal salaried manual positions are clearly predominant over informal positions (27.7 percent versus 15.3 percent).

11 The small size of the urban service and administrative classes becomes evident when we compare with European countries. In 2004, an average of 54 percent of workers in twenty-three European countries were members of these classes (Reference Bihagen, Nermo, Erikson, Rose and HarrisonBihagen, Nermo, and Erikson 2010, 95). The average for our sample of nine Latin American countries is 28.5 percent.

12 In the case of access to pension plans, most national surveys restrict their questions to salaried workers. The exceptions are Brazil, Chile, and Mexico, where access to pensions is part of a more general section asked to all adult respondents. This allows us to evaluate pension coverage among self-employed workers in these three countries.

13 An exception is Chile, where 64.4 percent of salaried workers in agriculture have a written labor contract, perhaps as a result of the expansion of modern agro-industrial firms.

14 We excluded Nicaragua because the available data on income did not include an integrated household income variable.

15 The low relative income of small employers in Mexico might be explained by a methodological problem in the survey questionnaire, which leads to the identification of informal self-employed workers with family helpers as small employers.

16 Two exceptions are Brazil and Ecuador, where the average income gap between formal and informal workers is roughly the same than the gap between skilled and unskilled workers.

17 The prevalence of relative poverty among these two classes may be overestimated, given the problems of underreporting of income among high income earners discussed earlier.

18 Even when our interpretation of a causal association between social class and living conditions is supported by our theoretical model and empirical analysis, the cross-sectional nature of our data is certainly a limitation for a stronger causal claim. Future studies must focus on analyzing unequal outcomes by social class with a longitudinal perspective.

19 There are some important exceptions, such as access to health insurance in Mexico, Chile, and Uruguay, which have been detached from social class through public health insurance programs not linked to the labor market. The question that arises in these countries is whether the quality and effective access to services is similar or varies significantly across social classes. In these cases, class inequalities might still be relevant but are expressed in the form of unequal inclusion rather than exclusion.

References

Balán, Jorge, Browning, Harley L., and Jelin, Elizabeth. 1977. El hombre en una sociedad en desarrollo: Movilidad geográfica y social en Monterrey. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica.Google Scholar
Barba Solano, Carlos. 2013. “Inseguridad y protección social en los países desarrollados y en América Latina.” Revista Mexicana de Sociología 75 (1): 2961.Google Scholar
Beccaría, Luis A. 2007. La medición del ingreso para los estudios de pobreza en América Latina: Aspectos conceptuales y empíricos. Santiago de Chile: Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL).Google Scholar
Behrman, Jere R., Gaviria, Alejandro, Székely, Miguel, Birdsall, Nancy, and Galiani, Sebastián. 2001. “Intergenerational Mobility in Latin America.” Economia 2 (1): 144. DOI: 10.1353/eco.2001.0010Google Scholar
Benavides, Martín. 2002. “Cuando los extremos no se encuentran: Un análisis de la movilidad social e igualdad de oportunidades en el Perú contemporáneo.” Bulletin de l’Institut Français d’Études Andines 31 (3): 473494. DOI: 10.4000/bifea.6600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bihagen, Erik, Nermo, Magnus, and Erikson, Robert. 2010. “Social Class and Employment Relations: Comparisons between the ESeC and EGP Class Schemas Using European Data.” In Social Class in Europe: An Introduction to the European Socio-Economic Classification, edited by Rose, David and Harrison, Eric, 89113. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Blossfeld, Hans-Peter, ed. 2008. Young Workers, Globalization and the Labor Market: Comparing Early Working Life in Eleven Countries. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Boado, Marcelo. 2008. La movilidad social en el Uruguay contemporáneo. Montevideo: Universidad de la República.Google Scholar
Breman, Jan, and Linden, Marcel. 2014. “Informalizing the Economy: The Return of the Social Question at a Global Level.” Development and Change 45 (5): 920940. DOI: 10.1111/dech.12115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cetrángolo, Óscar. 2014. “Financiamiento fragmentado, cobertura desigual y falta de equidad en el sistema de salud argentino.” Revista de Economía Política de Buenos Aires (13): 38.Google Scholar
Chávez Molina, Eduardo, ed. 2013. Desigualdad y movilidad social en el mundo contemporáneo: Aportes empíricos y conceptuales: Argentina, China, España, Francia. Buenos Aires: Imago Mundi.Google Scholar
Chávez Molina, Eduardo, and Sacco, Nicolás. 2015. “Reconfiguraciones en la estructura social: dos décadas de cambios en los procesos distributivos: Análisis del GBA según el clasificador de clases ocupacionales basado en la heterogeneidad estructural 1992–2013. In Hora de balance: Proceso de acumulación, mercado de trabajo y bienestar, Argentina, 2002–2014, edited by Lindemboim, Javier and Salvia, Agustín, 289316. Buenos Aires, Argentina: Editorial Universitaria de Buenos Aires (EUDEBA).Google Scholar
Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL). 2010. La hora de la igualdad, heterogeneidad estructural y brechas de productividad: De la fragmentación a la convergencia. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.Google Scholar
Cortés, Fernando. 2000. “La metamorfosis de los marginales: La polémica sobre el sector informal en América Latina.” En Tratado latinoamericano de sociología del trabajo, edited by de la Garza Toledo, Enrique, 592618. Mexico City: El Colegio de México, Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales, Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana, Fondo de Cultura Económica. DOI: 10.2307/j.ctv6mtcq4.6Google Scholar
Cortés, Fernando, and Escobar, Agustín. 2005. “Movilidad social intergeneracional en el México urbano.” Revista de la CEPAL 85: 149167. DOI: 10.18356/e53927eb-esCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cortés, Fernando, and Cuéllar, Óscar. 1990. Crisis y reproducción social. Mexico City: Miguel A. Porrúa.Google Scholar
Costa Ribeiro, Carlos Antonio. 2007. Estrutura de classe e mobilidade social no Brasil. São Paulo: Editora da Universidade do Sagrado Coração (EDUSC).Google Scholar
Cotlear, Daniel, Gómez-Dantés, Octavio, Knaul, Felicia, Atun, Rifat, Barreto, Ivana C., Cetrángolo, Óscar, Cueto, Marcos, Francke, Pedro, Frenz, Patricia, Guerrero, Ramiro, Lozano, Rafael, Marten, Robert, and Sáenz, Rocío. 2015. “Overcoming Social Segregation in Health Care in Latin America.” Lancet 385 (9974): 12481259. DOI: 10.1016/S0140-6736(14)61647-0CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Davies, Rhys, and Elias, Peter. 2010. “The Application of ESeC to Three Sources of Comparative European Data.” In Social Class in Europe: An Introduction to the European Socio-Economic Classification, edited by Rose, David and Harrison, Eric, 6186. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
De Oliveira, Orlandina, and García, Brígida. 1998. “Crisis, reestructuración económica y transformación de los mercados de trabajo en México.” Papeles de Población 4 (15): 3972.Google Scholar
Di Filippo, Armando, and Jadue, Santiago. 1976. “La heterogeneidad estructural: Concepto y dimensiones.” El Trimestre Económico 43 (169): 167214.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, and Goldthorpe, John H.. 1992. The Constant Flux: A Study of Class Mobility in Industrial Societies. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, Goldthorpe, John H., and Portocarero, Lucienne. 1979. “Intergenerational Class Mobility in Three Western European Societies.” British Journal of Sociology 30 (4): 415441. DOI: 10.2307/589632CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Espinoza, Vicente. 2006. “La movilidad ocupacional en el Cono Sur: Oportunidades y desigualdad social.” Revista de Sociología 20: 131146. DOI: 10.5354/0719-529X.2006.27534Google Scholar
Espinoza, Vicente, Barozet, Emmanuelle, and Méndez, María Luisa. 2013. “Estratificación y movilidad social bajo un modelo neoliberal: El caso de Chile.” Lavboratorio (25): 169191.Google Scholar
Feito Alonso, R. 1995. Estructura social contemporánea: Las clases sociales en los países industrializados. Madrid: Siglo XXI.Google Scholar
Ferreira, Francisco H., Messina, Julian, Rigolini, Jamele, López-Calva, Luis Felipe, Lugo, María Ana, and Vakis, Renos. 2012. Economic Mobility and the Rise of the Latin American Middle Class. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-9634-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fields, Gary S., and Ok, Efe A.. 1996. “The Meaning and Measurement of Income Mobility.” Journal of Economic Theory 71: 349377. DOI: 10.1006/jeth.1996.0125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gasparini, Leonardo, and Tornarolli, Leopoldo. 2009. “Labor Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean: Patterns and Trends from Household Survey Microdata.” Desarrollo y Sociedad (63): 1380. DOI: 10.13043/dys.63.1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaviria, Alejandro, and Dahan, Momi. 2001. “Sibling Correlations and Social Mobility in Latin America.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 49 (3): 537554. DOI: 10.1086/452514Google Scholar
Gerber, Theodore P., and Hout, Michael. 2004. “Tightening Up: Declining Class Mobility during Russia’s Market Transition.” American Sociological Review 69 (5): 677703. DOI: 10.1177/000312240406900504CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Germani, Gino. 1963. “La movilidad social en la Argentina.” In Movilidad social en la sociedad industrial, edited by Lipset, Seymour Martin and Bendix, Reinhard, 317367. Buenos Aires: Editorial Universitaria de Buenos Aires (EUDEBA).Google Scholar
Goldthorpe, John H., Halsey, Albert H., Heath, Anthony F., Ridge, John M., Bloom, Leonard, and Jones, F. Lancaster. 1982. Social Mobility and Class Structure in Modern Britain. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Grusky, David B. 1994. “The Contours of Social Stratification.” In Social Stratification in Sociological Perspective, edited by Grusky, David B., 335. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Grusky, David B., and Ravi Kanbur. 2006. Poverty and Inequality. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güveli, Ayse, Need, Ariana, and De Graaf, Nan Dirk. 2007. “The Rise of New Social Classes within the Service Class in the Netherlands: Political Orientation of Social and Cultural Specialists and Technocrats between 1970 and 2003.” Acta Sociologica 50 (2): 129146. DOI: 10.1177/0001699307077655CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaimes, Carlos Luis Moreno, and Flamand, Laura. 2016. “Towards Health-Care Equality? The Performance of Seguro Popular in Mexico (2003–2013).” Journal of Public Governance and Policy: Latin American Review 1 (2): 531.Google Scholar
Jorrat, Jorge Raúl. 2000. Estratificación social y movilidad: Un estudio del Área Metropolitana de Buenos Aires. Tucumán, Argentina: Universidad Nacional de Tucumán.Google Scholar
Jorrat, Jorge Raúl. 2008. “Exploraciones sobre movilidad de clases en Argentina, 2003–2004.” Documentos de Trabajo 52. Buenos Aires: Instituto Gino Germani, Universidad de Buenos Aires.Google Scholar
Labbens, Jean, and Solari, Aldo E.. 1961. “Movilidad social en Montevideo.” Boletín del Centro Latinoamericano de Pesquisas em Ciencias Sociais 4 (4): 349376.Google Scholar
León, Arturo, and Martínez, Javier. 2001. La estratificación social chilena hacia fines del siglo XX. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.Google Scholar
Londoño, Juan Luis, and Frenk, Julio. 1997. “Structured Pluralism: Towards an Innovative Model for Health System Reform in Latin America.” Health Policy 41 (1): 136. DOI: 10.1016/S0168-8510(97)00010-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López-Calva, Luis Felipe, and Ortiz-Juarez, Eduardo. 2014. “A Vulnerability Approach to the Definition of the Middle Class.” Journal of Economic Inequality 12 (1): 2347. DOI: 10.1007/s10888-012-9240-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez Franzoni, Juliana. 2006. “Regímenes de bienestar en América Latina: Consideraciones generales e itinerarios regionales.” Revista Centroamericana de Ciencias Sociales 2 (2).Google Scholar
Muñoz, Humberto, and de Oliveira, Orlandina. 1973. “Migración interna y movilidad ocupacional en la Ciudad de México.” Demografía y Economía 7 (2): 135148. DOI: 10.24201/edu.v7i02.214Google Scholar
Pastore, José. 1979. Desigualdade e mobilidade social no Brasil. São Paulo: Editorial Universidade de São Paulo.Google Scholar
Pastore, José, and do Valle Silva, Nelson. 2000. Mobilidade social no Brasil. São Paulo: Makron Books.Google Scholar
Pinto, Anibal. 1973. Heterogeneidad estructural y modelo de desarrollo reciente de la América Latina. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica.Google Scholar
Portes, Alejandro. 1985. “Latin American Class Structures: Their Composition and Change during the Last Decades.” Latin American Research Review 20 (3): 739.Google Scholar
Portes, Alejandro, and Hoffman, Kelly. 2003. “Latin American Class Structures: Their Composition and Change during the Neoliberal Era.” Latin American Research Review 38 (1): 4182. DOI: 10.1353/lar.2003.0011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portes, Alejandro, Castells, Manuel, and Benton, Lauren. 1989. “The Policy Implications of Informality.” In The Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developed Countries, edited by Portes, Alejandro, Castells, Manuel, and Benton, Lauren, 298311. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Portes, Alejandro, and Schauffler, Richard. 1993. “Competing Perspectives on the Latin American Informal Sector.” Population and Development Review 19 (1): 3360. DOI: 10.2307/2938384CrossRefGoogle Scholar
PREALC (Programa Regional del Empleo para América Latina y el Caribe). 1978. Sector informal: Funcionamiento y políticas. Santiago de Chile: PREALC.Google Scholar
Raczynski, Dagmar. 1972. “Migration, Mobility, and Occupational Achievement: The Case of Santiago, Chile.” International Migration Review 6 (2): 182198. DOI: 10.1177/019791837200600206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, David, and Harrison, Eric. 2014. Social Class in Europe: An Introduction to the European Socio-Economic Classification. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, Mike, Devine, Fiona, Cunningham, Niall, Taylor, Mark, Li, Yaojun, Hjellbrekke, Johs, Le Roux, Brigitte, Friedman, Sam, and Miles, Andrew. 2013. “A New Model of Social Class? Findings from the BBC’s Great British Class Survey Experiment.” Sociology 47 (2): 219250. DOI: 10.1177/0038038513481128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scalon, Maria C. 1999. Mobilidade social no Brasil: Padrões e tendências. Rio de Janeiro: Revan, Instituto Universitário de Pesquisas do Rio de Janeiro (IUPERJ), Universidade Candido Mendes (UCAM).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1955. Imperialism and Social Classes: Two Essays. New York: Meridian.Google Scholar
Solís, Patricio. 2005. “Cambio estructural y movilidad ocupacional en Monterrey, México.” Estudios Sociológicos 23 (67): 4374.Google Scholar
Solís, Patricio, and Benza, Gabriela. 2013. “Classes sociales, pauvreté et inégalités dans les années de l’alternance présidentielle.” Problèmes d’Amérique Latine (2): 3353. DOI: 10.3917/pal.089.0033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solís, Patricio, and Boado, Marcelo. 2016. Y sin embargo se mueve: Estratificación y movilidad intergeneracional de clase en América Latina. Mexico City: El Colegio de México, Centro de Estudios Espinosa Yglesias.Google Scholar
Tokman, Víctor E. 1992. Beyond Regulation: The Informal Economy in Latin America. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.Google Scholar
Tokman, Víctor E. 1995. El sector informal en América Latina: Dos décadas de análisis. Mexico City: Consejo Nacional para la Cultura y las Artes.Google Scholar
Torche, Florencia. 2005. “Unequal but Fluid: Social Mobility in Chile in Comparative Perspective.” American Sociological Review 70 (3): 422450. DOI: 10.1177/000312240507000304Google Scholar
Torche, Florencia. 2006. “Una clasificación de clases para la sociedad chilena”. Revista de Sociología 20: 1543. DOI: 10.5354/0719-529X.2006.27529Google Scholar
Torche, Florencia. 2014. “Intergenerational Mobility and Inequality: The Latin American Case.” Annual Review of Sociology 40: 619642. DOI: 10.1146/annurev-soc-071811-145521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torche, Florencia, and Wormald, Guillermo. 2004. Estratificación y movilidad social en Chile: entre la adscripción y el logro. Santiago de Chile: Serie Políticas Sociales, CEPAL.Google Scholar
Wagstaff, Adam, Cotlear, Daniel, Eozenou, Patrick Hoang-Vu, and Buisman, Leander R.. 2016. “Measuring Progress towards Universal Health Coverage: With an Application to 24 Developing Countries.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 32 (1): 147189. DOI: 10.1093/oxrep/grv019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weller, Jürgen. 2000. Reformas económicas, crecimiento y empleo: Los mercados de trabajo en América Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL. DOI: 10.18356/57c4677b-esGoogle Scholar
Weller, Jürgen. 2014. Aspectos de la evolución reciente de los mercados laborales de América Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL. DOI: 10.18356/a9d20244-esGoogle Scholar
Wodtke, Geoffrey T. 2016. “Social Class and Income Inequality in the United States: Ownership, Authority, and Personal Income Distribution from 1980 to 2010.” American Journal of Sociology 121 (5): 13751415. DOI: 10.1086/684273CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wresinski, Joseph. 1987. Grande pauvreté et précarité économique et sociale: Séances des 10 et 11 février 1987. Paris: Direction des Journaux Officiels.Google Scholar
Wright, Erik O. 1997. Class Counts: Comparative Studies in Class Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Adjustments to the EGP social class schema for Latin America.

Figure 1

Table 2 Adapted EGP schema for Latin America.

Figure 2

Table 3 Class structure in Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Figure 3

Table 4 Percentage of salaried workers with written labor contract by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Figure 4

Table 5 Percentage of workers contributing to a pension plan by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Figure 5

Table 6 Percentage of workers subscribed to a health insurance plan* by social class, Latin American countries, working population ages 15–64, 2011–2015.

Figure 6

Table 7 Relative income share of household per capita income by social class, Latin American countries, 2011–2015.

Figure 7

Table 8 Percentage of households in relative poverty by social class, Latin American countries, 2011–2015.

Figure 8

Table A1 Data sources.